
© Council for the Development of
Social Science Research in Africa, 2012
(ISSN 0850-3907)
Globalisation,
Economic Reforms and Democracy in Nigeria
Chuku Umezurike*
Abstract
This article
explores how the forces of globalisation have been undermining democratic
struggles in Nigeria, particularly through the economic reforms of the Nigerian
state. First, the study involves a theoretical demonstration of these
relationships. Second, it notes that the relationships between the forces of
globalisation and democracy in Nigeria are largely confrontational. This is the
case in so far as preindustrial mercantilism, British colonialism, the current
transnational effects of foreign direct investment and the multilateral
management of contemporary global order have collectively been undermining the
democratic struggles of domestic social forces in Nigeria. The study further
establishes that there is largely a supportive and reinforcing relationship
between the forces of globalisation and economic reform protocols in Nigeria.
It finally suggests that although democratic forces in Nigeria have been
inducing economic reforms in the country, reform protocols have been
reactionary to the forces of democratisation. An analysis of the various
economic reforms in Nigeria as a demonstration of this theoretical framework
forms the second broad section of the paper. There is also a categorisation of
these reforms into two, namely, those that have inadvertently been pursuing
economic nationalism of the Nigerian governing elites and those that have
directly been structured and oriented towards advancing market liberalisation
and state divestiture. Included in the first category are: indigenisation and
Nigerianisation; land use; and reforms for poverty alleviation. In the second
category are: austerity measures, structural adjustment programme,
privatisation and commercialisation which have been embodied in the Structural
Adjustment Programmes (SAP) and also in the current practices, the National
Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS) and trade and financial
liberalisations orchestrated in SAP and post-SAP engagements. The study finally
notes that the democratisation of economic reforms in the developing countries
is central to genuine global governance.

*
Department of Political Science, University of Nigeria, Nsukka. Email:
chuku.umezurike@unn.edu.ng
26
Résumé
Cet article
examine comment les forces de la mondialisation sapent dans le temps les luttes
démocratiques à travers les réformes économiques de l’Etat, en particulier au
Nigeria. En premier lieu, l’étude incorpore une démonstration théorique de ces
relations. Elle note ensuite que les relations entre les forces de la
mondialisation et celles de la démocratie sont largement conflictuelles. Tel
est le cas dans la mesure où le mercantilisme préindustriel, le colonialisme
britannique, les effets actuels de l’investissement direct étranger et la
gestion multilatérale de l’ordre mondial contemporain ont collectivement
fragilisé dans le temps les combats démocratiques des forces sociales au
Nigeria. Ensuite, l’étude établit qu’il existe dans une grande mesure une relation
de soutien et de renforcement entre les forces de la mondialisation et les
protocoles de réforme économique au Nigeria. Enfin, elle soutient qu’alors que
les forces démocratiques au Nigeria induisaient des réformes économiques dans
le pays, les protocoles de réformes leur ont été réactionnaires. Une analyse
des différentes réformes économiques au Nigeria comme démonstration de ce cadre
théorique forme la seconde grande partie de cet article. Il y a aussi une
catégorisation des ces réformes en deux, notamment, celles qui par inadvertance
poursuivaient un nationalisme économique des élites gouvernantes nigérianes et
celle qui ont été directement structurées et orientées vers le développement de
la libéralisation du marché et le désinvestissement de l’Etat. Compris dans la
première catégorie sont : l’autochtonisation et la nigérianisation,
l’utilisation du foncier, et les réformes pour la lutte contre la pauvreté. On
trouve dans la deuxième catégorie les mesures d’austérité, le programme
d’ajustement structurel (PAS), la privatisation et la commercialisation qui ont
été incorporé dans le PAS et également dans les pratiques actuelles, la
National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS) [Stratégie
Nationale d’Autonomisation et de
Développement Economique] et les libéralisations commerciales et financières
orchestrées dans les engagements PAS et post-PAS. L’étude note en dernier lieu
que la démocratisation des réformes économiques dans les pays en développement
est essentielle à une véritable gouvernance mondiale.
Introduction
There is an unsettled gap in the literature
on the political economy of Africa, including especially Nigeria. This arises
from the dearth of studies on how the forces of globalisation via the economic
reforms of the Nigerian state have been undermining democracy in this society.
The studies on globalisation in Africa have been lively, progressive but
largely generating contentious issues for further enquiry. For instance,
studies on the Structural Adjustment Programmes (SAPs) in Africa, described as
emerging under the spell of globalisation, have raised very important issues
that need to be further investigated. Specifically, the links between
globalisation and the SAPs and the negative implications of the latter for
development in Africa, including Nigeria, have been extensively discussed (see
for instance Aina, et al. 2004). But the SAPs have only embodied some of the
numerous economic reforms in Nigeria as in much of Africa. Despite acknowledged
similarities, economic
27
reforms in Africa have been largely volatile
and contradictory primarily because they respond both to the laws of the free
market and to domestic social struggle.
Even though dominant, economic reforms may not always be
conflated with the free market. This trend may not always conform with the laws
of history as it could be expected that reforms could reproduce various degrees
of democratic struggles which may run in contrariness to the free market in
given countries. So far in Nigeria, even though much of the economic reforms
have been reproducing the global requirements of the free market, the
cruciality of the democratic struggles of the Nigerian people in characterising
these reforms may not be underestimated. Thus, it is important to bring into
analysis those distinct economic reforms which had preceded the SAPs, including
particularly the indigenisation reforms. Subsequent ones such as the current
National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS) in Nigeria claim
some specificity, especially in the endeavours of sanitising the state, and
poverty alleviation. Thus, an appropriate problematisation of economic reform
in Nigeria, its links with the forces of globalisation and its negative
implications for democratisation requires a compendium of the reforms.
A demonstration of the volatility and contradictions of the
economic reforms in Nigeria presents the necessity of their categorisation into
two, namely, the direct and the indirect ones. The direct ones are those which
have been outrightly structured, and mostly directly foisted by the
multilateral institutions to advance market liberalisation and state
‘divestiture’. This is the most conventional and numerous of the economic
reforms in Nigeria. The second category is the indirect ones. These are those
economic reforms which have been ostensibly designed to advance popular
struggles but have in practice been advancing petty bourgeois development in
Nigeria. The second category is the less conventional and apparently the
weaker, even though it has raised such pertinent issues as poverty alleviation.
The major thrust of the study is to problematise economic
reforms in Nigeria, first, as being largely shaped by the forces of
globalisation and, second, as being largely reversals of democratic struggles
in the country. This thrust involves a further demonstration that the gross
weaknesses of the reforms for popular struggles correlates positively with the
weakness of Nigeria in the global political economy and the limited democratic
value of domestic petty bourgeois governance. A combination of these realities
underscores the extremely high degree of limitations on democracy by the forces
of globalisation in Nigeria.
Through these efforts, it is expected that the controversies
surrounding the actual roles of the forces of globalisation in the development
of such
28
countries as Nigeria could have been much
more revisited. Moreover, the study would attempt to unmask the obscurantism
that have been surrounding economic reforms by establishing that even though
economic reforms have been largely informed by the democratic struggles of the
Nigerian people, the reform protocols have been irreverently counteracting
these struggles. Thus, even when it has been suggested that economic reforms in
developing countries such as Nigeria are homegrown, the reform protocols have
yet been underscoring reactionary thrust towards the economic lives of the
population. This is highly ominous given that economic reforms have constituted
a highly significant proportion of the public policy process of developing
countries, including Nigeria. It is even all the more ominous in that the
limitations of economic reforms for advancing democracy in the various
countries of the developing world undermine their prospects of advancing global
integration and harmonisation which have been argued to be at the heart of
globalisation.
To begin with, there are studies that have raised
significant issues bothering on this subject of interest whose brief review
facilitates conceptualisation and clarifies the problem. These studies have
been classified into four. They include first and foremost those studies that
have dwelt on the negative implications of globalisation for the development of
the global South. They also include the studies that have characterised and
contextualised underdevelopment, particularly in Africa, without necessarily
bothering with the global implications of these realities. The third
categorisation are those studies which have attempted an exploration of the
links between globalisation and the state in a broad analytical framework. The
fourth and last category of literature here are those studies that have treated
specific economic reforms (with the Structural Adjustment Programmes of the
mid-1980s dominating) and the global implications.
Scholars in the developing world, especially those of
dependencia persuasion, have been at the forefront of the studies on the
negative implications of globalisation for the overall development of the
global South. These scholars have been mainly reacting to the postulations and
prognostications of the Modernisation School and classical economics. Samr Amin
(see, for instance, Amin 1990, 1998) has certainly been one of the greatest
influences of this school. Much more recently, the following studies have
provided meaningful contributions here: Asobie (2001), Aaron (2001), Offiong
(2001), Khor (2001), Mander and Goldsmith (eds 1996). Asobie (2001) clearly
hits the nail on the head by noting that the divide on the implications of
globalisation for the development of the South revolves around the
developmental divide between the North and the South. For the former,
globalisation has been necessary especially in so far as it has involved
29
‘…increasing volume and variety of
transnational transactions, in goods and services, in international capital
flows, in human migration and through a widespread diffusion of technology’
(Asobie 2001:37).
Intellectual subscriptions of globalisation failures to the
development of the South have been suggesting that ‘not only has globalisation
divided the populations of many countries into winners and losers, but it has
also divided regions of the world into winners and sad losers. Certainly,
Africa is a loser region (Offiong 2001:3). Corroborating this stand, Asobie (2001)
observes that:
In Africa in particular,
workers’ unions are against full scale integration into the process of
globalisation. Under the umbrella of the Organisation of African Trade Union
Unity (OATUU), African workers have risen against African states’ membership of
the World Trade Organization (WTO). In 2001, African trade unions threatened to
disrupt the WTO ministerial conference in Doha, Qatar because of the WTO’s
support of globalisation (Asobie 2001:45).
In Nigeria, the Nigerian Labour Congress
(NLC) threatened to call out workers on strike to protest against, and
frustrate the Nigerian government’s intention to re-negotiate the WTO treaty.
The workers’ unions seem mostly poised against the WTO in particular terms and
globalisation in general terms.
Scholars on the negative implications of globalisation in
the South generally and Africa in particular have noted the unpreparedness of
these societies to cope with its requirements. Khor (2001) has thus suggested
the reasons to include: weaknesses arising from colonial hangover, heavy
external indebtedness, dependence on foreign donors leading to limited capacity
to embark on meaningful international bargaining and negotiations among others.
These reasons tally with the position of the Malaysian Permanent Representative
to the United Nations, Razali Ismail:
At a meeting of the UN
Economic and Social Council at Geneva on 3rd July, 1997, the latter developed
the argument that the issue of globalisation should not be addressed with a
view to maintaining the global status quo. Rather, it should be placed squarely
in the context of the higher issue of ‘growth and development with justice’.
The Ambassador maintained that when this is done, it should be realised that
not all developing countries are ready for integration into the globalising
capitalist system (Asobie 2001:42).
The second strand of the literature reviewed
here has significant relationship with the first. This second strand, as has
been noted, deals with those studies which have characterised and
contextualised underdevelopment especially in Africa. On Nigeria in particular,
serious efforts in this direction have included Nnoli (1981, 1993), Nore and
Turner (eds 1980), Turner (1981), Umezurike (2010), among others. The comprador
character of the political economy as an undercurrent of underdevelopment in
Nigeria has been quite elaborately presented in Turner (1980). For Turner (in
Nore and Turner 1980),
30
from independence, Nigeria
has been governed by a neo-colonial comprador state which lacks coherence and
stability… Compradors are those professional intermediaries who organise the
access of foreign traders to the local market. Nigerian middlemen constitute a
comprador class. Representatives of this class occupy government posts and
control the state…compradors can be divided into statists who exclude the
private middleman from state transactions with foreign firms and collaborators
who join with private middlemen in carrying out these transactions (Turner
1980:204).
In agreement with Turner, the Nigerian
political economy has been a comprador economy par excellence. It is this
condition of existence that largely underscores the crisis of development in
this political economy. For in reality, the comprador nature derives ‘from its
overall orientation towards facilitating commerce, from its domination by
representatives of the local middleman class, and from the intermediary role
its officers play between foreign salesmen and the local (state and final
consumer) market’ (Nore and Turner 1980:205).
Despite the persistence of the comprador political economy
in Nigeria as in much of Africa, neoclassical economics and the Modernisation
school have for long held a wrong perception of the prospects of development.
For these analysts, the Nigerian economy has passed the stage of economic
take-off and reached that of self-sustaining growth. But this has not been the
case. In an edited work entitled Dead-end
to Nigerian Development, Okwudiba Nnoli correctly observed that:
The oil boom of 1973-1977
created an illusion of national wealth and individual affluence, which we
believed would sooner or later burst into the reality of the nation’s grinding
poverty. However, we did not foresee that the bubble of wealth would burst that
early and that by 1982 the country would be pursuing economic policies of
austerity (Nnoli 1993:ix).
For Nigeria and indeed much of Africa, the
comprador character of development has been historically complemented by the
external orientation of such development and the fact that these political
economies are tied to the centre of global capitalist development as peripheral
appendage of that development. This thrust has been least prepared for
globalisation as indeed the latter has been leading to the recompradorisation
of development in these societies.
The third classification of literature to be considered here
are those studies which have attempted analytical links between globalisation
and the state. Particularly notable here are Strange (1997), Keller and Pauly
(1997). Indeed these two were the most related out of a whole lot of other
incisive works on the subject of globalisation which a particular volume of the
1997 edition of Current History
covered. Strange (1997) and Keller and Pauly (1997) differed in their analyses
of the relationship between globalisation and the
31
state. While the former submitted that
globalisation has actually been leading to the decline of the state, the latter
argued in a different direction. For Strange (1997):
There are three main areas in
which state authority has declined…the first is defense: the security of
society from violence. The second is finance: the preservation of money as a
reliable means of exchange, unit of account, and as store of value…the third is
the provision of welfare: the assurance that some of the benefits of greater
wealth go to the poor, the weak, the sick, and the old (Keller 1997:368).
The author summed up that the society is at
the mercy of big business given that globalisation has undermined ‘the state’s
power to provide economic and financial stability, to protect the vulnerable in
society and to preserve the environment’ (Strange 1997:369).
In countering the above, Keller and Pauly (1997) observes
that ‘markets or more precisely huge sprawling commercial hierarchies are not
replacing states as the world’s effective government, nor are corporations
becoming more democratic’ (1997:375). The authors illustrate their thesis of
persisting state roles in spite of globalisation by noting that the:
…increasing
openness of corporate markets must be associated with more deliberate efforts
to manage the consequences… and that efficient and stable global markets will
not likely evolve through the unhindered competition of globe-spanning firms
when national institutions and ideologies remain decisive inside those
firms (Keller and Pauly 1997:375).
The disagreement between Strange (1997) and
Keller and Pauly (1997) tend to revolve around the trends of disagreement
between scholars of political economy on the one hand and those of
international relations on the other. While the former has mostly been
expounding what has usually been referred to as ‘global tyranny’, the latter
have mostly been persisting in their submission that the state still remains
invincible despite globalisation. What is important to this study is to note
that even though the barriers of nationstates are been bombarded by the forces
of globalisation, the diminishing roles of the state is only state fetishism.
The state as a mode of domination and as a social relation has essentially been
perpetuating its roles in the global accumulation process. Perhaps this reality
would have been more obvious if these studies had concentrated on the links
between globalisation and concrete state forms. This is important because both
theses of ‘global tyranny’ and ‘persisting state roles’ have been
representations of specific forms of democratic struggles that are taking place
in this contemporary global age.
This leads us to the fourth and last classification of the
literature for this study. These are studies which have focused on specific
economic reforms including especially the Structural Adjustment Programmes
(SAP) of the
32
mid-1980s in sub-Saharan Africa and their
global implications. Prominent here are Asobie (1988), Onimode (1992), Olukoshi
(ed.1993), Blomstrom and Lundahl (1993), Shaw (1993), and Aina et al (eds
2004). The study by Asobie (Asobie
1988) is particularly important here because unlike most others it studied the
indigenisation reforms in Nigeria. These reforms he noted did not go beyond the
reproduction of the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie which really never advanced
democracy in the country. But, as he further observed, this trend was even
further undermined by the forces of globalisation. Asobie (1988) however has close resemblance
with Onimode (1992) and Olukoshi (1993) especially in locating the significant
roles of the global political economy in the economic reforms that they
studied.
But as has been noted, the SAPs attracted the most attention
in this scholarship. A number of reasons could be adduced for this. The first
is that out of all the economic reforms, SAPs has been the most universally
widespread not just in Africa but across all of the developing political
economies. Second, and related to the first above, is that the SAPs had been
specifically foisted on these political economies by the Bretton Woods
institutions. In other words, the various SAPs had been policy documents of
these institutions. Third, in terms of depth, the SAPs would certainly rank
topmost especially in the sense that their policy thrust penetrated a wide
range of economic issues in the countries in which they have been applied.
Fourth and finally, the SAPs expectedly created the most far-reaching political
upheavals and of course contentions in the academic circles. The literature on
the SAPs has been appropriately phased:
The first, lasting until
1986-87, was dominated by studies of economic reforms’ macro-economic impact.
The period 1986-89 saw the publication of a number of works focusing more on
their social welfare impact, particularly in relation to what are commonly
called the vulnerable groups. From 1989-90 onward sectoral-level economic
studies and work on the politics of adjustment became more common, written both
from implementation-centered and broader political impact-centered
perspectives. Simultaneously, efforts have emerged to think through certain
national adjustment processes in relation to broader economic, social and
political changes (Gibbon 1993:11, see also Gibbon and Ponte 2005).
These observations on the literature agree
with two related contributions to the subject which are contained in Aina et al
(eds 2004). These two are Adejumobi (2004) which dwelt on ‘Economic
Globalisation, Market Reforms and Social Welfare Services in West Africa’ and
Ndiaye (2004) whose study was ‘Economic Reforms and Social Policies in
Senegal’. In the judgment of Adejumobi (2004:32), ‘the introduction of the
Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) was the most decisive factor in the
reconstitution and decline of state spending in the social sector’. This is
collaborated by Ndiaye (2004:114) who noted that ‘…it is possible to state that
Senegalese society
33
and economy have been profoundly and
negatively affected by the continued implementation of SAP, especially its
structural reforms implementation component’. Adejumobi (2004) did not fail to
make an allusion to the crucial links between SAP and globalisation for the
author indeed agrees with Mihevc (1995) in describing SAP as the
‘fundamentalist economic doctrine emerging under the spell of globalisation…’
(Adejumobi 2004:32).
Relevant as they could be, the studies of the SAPs, as
outcomes of globalisation with the due recognition of their negative
implications especially in social service delivery in Africa, leave much more
to be desired in the problematisation of the links between globalisation, economic
reforms and democracy in Nigeria, as even in much of Africa. The first reason
for this is that even though detailed in scope, SAP does not cover crucial
reforms for economic nationalism whose reform protocols are quite crucial for
analysis here. Second, despite the insinuation that the Nigerian SAP has been
continuous even till date, sufficient evidence abounds to give benefit of
doubts to policy makers in Nigeria on certain peculiarities of subsequent
economic reforms, including in particular the National Economic Empowerment and
Development Strategy (NEEDS). In
summary, therefore, available knowledge on the SAPs in Africa does not solely
equip us to deal with the volatility and contradictions underscored in Nigeria’s
economic reforms, their relationships with the historical forces of
globalisation and their overall negative implications for democracy in the
country. The study progresses to develop a theoretical framework of analysis.
Globalisation,
Economic Reforms and Democracy in Nigeria:
A Theoretical Framework of Analysis
The focus of this section is to build a theoretical model
for analysing how the forces of globalisation via the economic reforms of the
Nigerian state have been undermining democracy in Nigeria. To begin with, the
various concepts in use have to be defined. Globalisation here stands for the
processes through which capital has been universalised and internationalised,
resulting in higher quest for boundary-broadening among agents of production
(see, for instance, Rosenau 1997; Asobie 2001; Umezurike 2008). Historically,
the forces of globalisation in Nigeria have included the following:
• Mercantilist
capital whose phenomenal roles were mostly observable between the mid-15th and
late 18th centuries.
• European
national capital assisted by multinational corporations whose objects were
mostly realised via colonisation especially between the 19th and mid-20th
centuries.
34
• Transnationalism
and multilateral institutions, including the World Bank and the IMF. The modus
operandi of transnationalism has been via foreign direct investments, including
technological transfer and global financial management by the multilateral
institutions. Their roles have mostly postdated the Second World War.
The second concept of interest here is
economic reform. In this study, economic reform represents broad government
policy on the economy designed primarily but not exclusively at market
liberalisation. It has also involved variations in those activities related to
domestic production, distribution and exchange of goods in relation to internal
and external pressures (see Umezurike 2006). Even though definite historical
events underscore the character of economic reforms in Nigeria, specific
reforms have actually started from the post-independence era. These have
included the following:
• Indigenisation
and Nigerianisation reforms, 1960s, 1972, 1977 and beyond.
• Land
Use Reforms, 1978.
• Reforms
for Poverty Alleviation, 2000-continuing.
• Austerity
measures, 1982-84.
• Privatisation
and Commercialisation Reforms, 1980s, 1990s and beyond.
• Structural
Adjustment Programme, 1986-93.
• Reforms
embodied in the National Economic Empowerment and Development Strategy (NEEDS),
2004-2007.
• Trade
and financial liberalisations producing impetuses for exchange and interest
rate regimes and have spanned through numerous reforms far beyond the
neo-liberal era. The focus in this paper is however on the neo-liberal regime.
This study also takes into consideration
significant macroeconomic policies of the country as integral parts of these
reforms.
The last concept to be defined here is democracy. By
democracy is meant popular power (see Ake 1985, 2003; Umezurike 2006) encompassing
the following practices: rights and liberties, series of freedoms, including
freedom of speech, association among others, political spaces for interest
group negotiations, viable civil society, popular participation in governance,
free and fair electoral system. Democracy is here determined in terms of how
far these practices emerged from the engagements as well as define the
existence of the following social forces:
35
• The
Nigerian peasantry;
• The
Nigerian working class;
• The
Nigerian petty bourgeoisie; • Ethnic
groups in Nigeria.
There are three clear interpretations of the
relationships between the forces of globalisation, economic reforms and
domestic social forces in Nigeria. These are as follows:
• Confrontational
relationships between forces of globalisation and forces of democracy in
Nigeria;
• Supportive
and reinforcing relationships between forces of globalisation and economic
reforms in Nigeria;
• Inducement
and reactionary relationships between economic reforms and democratic forces in
Nigeria.
Confrontational Relationship between Forces of
Globalisation and Forces of Democracy in Nigeria
As Figure 1 shows, there is a
confrontational relationship between the forces of globalisation and the
domestic forces of democracy in Nigeria. The proof of the existence of this
largely confrontational relationship has been both historical and contemporary.
Historically, the forces of globalisation, including in particular mercantilism
and British colonialism, created the political and economic structures which
have over the years been undermining the forces of democracy in the country.
The first salient structure in this regard is the initiation of comprador
character of development during pre-industrial mercantilism. This took place
mainly between 1500 and 1799. In the various parts of what now constitutes
Nigeria, mercantilism stalled the requisite social structures for development.
For instance, the key articles of trade that were taken out were slaves, gold
and elephant tusks. Even though the economy had not been monetised at the time,
there were three key trade routes through which contacts with the outside world
were made: Trans Saharan, East African (Indian Ocean) and Trans Atlantic
routes.
The data on slave trade for all of Africa (different
countries had not emerged at the time) are readily available:
Between 1450 and 1900, a
total of 11.7 million African slaves on the annual rate of 26.0 thousand were
traded out of Africa. In 1791, a total of 15,108 slaves were loaded out of
which 1397 died representing a percentage mortality of 9.2. The profit level of
slave trade to the British was as much as 548,769 Pounds (or 8.3 percent
profit) between 1761 and 1770. Between 1791 and 1800, it had grown to 1,897,234
Pounds (or 13.0 percent) profit level. In the region of the Bight of Biafra,
the estimated slave export by Britain between 1761 and 1810 was 93.0 percent
Figure
1: A Model of the Interactions between Globalization, Democracy and
Economic Reform in Nigeria.

Source: The Author
37
leaving Portugal with 7.0
percent. In the Bight of Benin, British export for the same period was 18.3
percent, France 35.6 percent and Portugal 46.1 percent (see Anstey 1975:45-7
and Austen 1987:275).
The trade in slaves undermined requisite
processes for development in all of Africa. Slave raids led to wars and
all-round insecurity. Moreover, African development was mortgaged to the
advantages of those of Europe and North America. This was further consolidated
by British imperial conquest and the creation of a particular character of
state in Nigeria which has been undermining the forces of democracy.
Imperial conquest took place between 1800 and 1945. The
character of imperial conquest and subsequent colonisation for the period
consolidated comprador development through the maintenance-dissolution effects
produced on peasant production relations. Thus, there has been a conjunctive
exploitation of the political economy by imperial capital, traditional chiefs
and mercantile middlemen.
During colonial rule, British imperial capital exploited
peasant economy by subjecting it to produce cash crops for metropolitan
industrial manufactures. The major cash crops which were produced included palm
produce, cocoa, groundnut and cotton. The period postdating the Second World
War has been perpetuating the same character of political economy in Nigeria
fostered by transnational corporations, multilateral institutions, including
especially the IMF and the World Bank. The modus operandi has been via foreign
direct investment, foreign technological transfer and effective maintenance of
the current global financial order by the Bretton Woods institutions.
Nevertheless, the hallmark of Nigeria has remained unmitigated political
crisis, economic and technological dependence and debt crisis. While the
Nigerian petty bourgeoisie has remained the conveyor belt of this character of
development, they have equally fostered incessant ethnic conflicts and
undermined the development and political struggles of the working class in
Nigeria’s postcolony. Invariably, the direction of the largely confrontational
relationship has been such that both the forces of globalisation and the forces
of democracy have been mutually antagonistic. Part of this era has been the
neo-liberal regime in which these antagonisms have been mostly revealed.
Supportive and Reinforcing Relationships between
Forces of Globalisation and Economic Reforms in Nigeria
The economic reforms treated here are those
that postdate political independence in Nigeria. The principal reason for this
is that even though some residuary reforms during colonialism could be
deciphered prior to political independence, the form of Nigeria’s economy was
still emerging largely as an integral part of Europe and did not undergo
independent reforms as
38
such. For all of the colonial era, for
instance, and even a little beyond, Nigeria’s currency had been tied to that of
the British. Moreover, the process of integration of Nigeria to the global
political economy under the colonial order was unilaterally done and mostly via
political and administrative coercion. Understandably, the form and content of
the emerging Nigerian economy at the time were contested seriously at the
administrative and political realms. Those were the realms where reforms were
taking place.
For sure, there are
clear evidence of the existence of the specified character and direction of
relationships between economic reforms and the forces of globalisation, as has
been clearly shown in Figure 1 above. First, is that the character of economic
reforms is informed by the character of the political economy fostered by the
forces of globalisation. Second, is that the unfolding developments in the
reform protocols have been in conformity with the developments of the global
political economy. Third and finally, is that some of the contemporary forces
of globalisation have been central to the implementation of a number of these
economic reforms. The two arrows in Figure 1 thus show a mutuality of interests
and support in that axis.
To begin with the first above, it is important to note that
the comprador character of the political economy fostered by the forces of
globalisation has dominated the character of economic reforms in Nigeria. The
reforms for indigenisation and Nigerianisation were ostensibly designed to
create a domestic bourgeois class in contrariness to petty bourgeois domestic
governance in the country. But as will be shown later in the study, this never
materialised primarily because the efforts did not carry along with them
popular struggles of the Nigerian people.
Typical of comprador political economies, the Nigerian
economy which a number of these reforms have sought to address has not only
been built on narrow resource bases but has been externally oriented with low
intersectoral linkages. Too, its manufacturing base has been quite weak and
dominated by foreign direct investment and technology.
The major cash crops which have dominated the economy have
been palm produce, cocoa, groundnut and cotton. As from 1914 when palm produce,
groundnut and cocoa dominated the export earnings of Nigeria at the tune of
69.0 per cent, 3.0 per cent and 2.9 per
cent respectively, the dependence on narrow resources shifted to crude
petroleum principally in the 1960s and 1970s. In 1966, crude petroleum
contributed 43.3 per cent of Nigeria’s export earnings but quickly rose to 84.4
per cent in 1975 and 97.8 per cent in 1985. The near-absolute domination of
crude petroleum despite these reforms has continued till date (so much of these
data are found in the Annual Abstract of
Statistics of the National Bureau of Statistics for various years).
39
The second demonstration of the mutually supportive and
reinforcing relationships of the forces of globalisation and Nigeria’s economic
reforms has been from the fact that the reform protocols have been in
conformity with the developments in the global political economy. For instance,
the post-Second World War quests for transnationalism, multilateralism and the
preference for foreign direct investment to the unfettered roles of European
national capital and colonisation resulted in the supportive reforms of
Nigerianisation and indigenisation of the Nigerian economy. Also, the debt
crisis of developing political economies and its negative implications for the
global political economy remained at the hallmark of the Structural Adjustment
Programmes of the mid-1980s and beyond. Indeed, the SAPs in sub-Saharan Africa
emerged from a World Bank document prepared by its consultant, Eliot Berg.
Again, the third and last issue is that some of the more
contemporary forces of globalisation, including especially foreign direct
investment and the multilateral roles of the Bretton Woods institutions, have
been at the heart of the implementations of the economic reforms of the
Nigerian state. So far, successful external public debt negotiations of
Nigeria, a carrot of economic reform implementations have been hinged on prior
negotiations with the Bretton Woods institutions. The Paris Club had in 2006 granted debt concessions to Nigeria on
account of its persistent implementation of the reforms embodied in the NEEDS
in particular and aggressive deregulations in general.
Inducement and Reactionary Relationships between
Economic Reforms and Forces of Democracy in Nigeria
This is the last set of relationships
indicated here. It is shown in Figure 1 by two arrows one of which has a
uni-dimensional direction while the other has a bi-dimensional direction. In
these two reverse directions there is a portrayal that while the forces of
democracy in Nigeria produce inducement effects on economic reforms, the latter
in the reverse produce reactionary effects on the former. The proofs are
germane: the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie solely induced the reforms for
Indigenisation, Nigerianisation and Land Use. These reforms came in the
aftermath of political independence in Nigeria. The Nigerian petty bourgeoisie
not only sought to take full and effective control of the Nigerian public
sector but also sought to empower themselves economically. Thus, economic
nationalism remained the beacon of Indigenisation and Nigerianisation in
particular.
After close to two decades of domestic crisis-ridden
political governance, the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie sought to further enhance
its economic power by inducing the Land Use reform of 1978. But expectedly, the
reform
40
produced in large numbers urban land
speculators and absentee farmers in the rural area. The limited productive
capacity of the comprador economy and its historical dependence on peasant
agricultural production ensured the failure of the Land Use reform.
Reforms for poverty alleviation and sanitisation of the
Nigerian public sector as contained in the NEEDS reforms have been largely informed by the
historical struggles of the Nigerian people (the working class and the
peasantry in particular) against poverty, unemployment, rising inflationary
rates, and public sector corruption. Part of these (especially sanitising the
public sector) could have however been facilitated by the heavy presence of
retired military personnel in the most recent past of political governance in
Nigeria. The military, being an institution of the state, appears to have been
producing higher inducements for the sanitisation of the Nigerian state rather
than its overwhelming ‘divestiture’ from the economy.
There is also provenance of the reactionary roles of
economic reforms on the forces of democracy in Nigeria. As will be shown, even
though the indigenisation and Nigerianisation reforms succeeded in the mass
reproduction of the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie, the reforms remained incapable
of their reasonable empowerment vis-à-vis metropolitan capital. Their roles in
the economy were still restricted to artisanal and agency roles to metropolitan
capital.
In consonance with the above, the reforms for privatisation
and commercialisation have not succeeded in empowering the Nigerian elites in
so far as their roles in global trade, over-reliance on foreign direct
investment and technology are still persisting. The growing trends in poverty
in contradistinction to the reforms for poverty alleviation have already been
documented (see, for instance, Umezurike 2006).
In the light of the above, the study advances to further the
enquiry by examining how specific economic reforms in Nigeria have been
facilitating differing degrees of global limitations on its democracy.
Global Limitations on Democracy in Nigeria:
Analysis of Economic Reforms
An examination of specific economic reforms
in Nigeria shows that the extent to which these reforms have been supportive
and reinforcing the forces of globalisation has equally represented similar
extent to which the forces of globalisation have been undermining domestic
democratic struggles in the country. An obverse manner of stating this reality
is that despite the inducement of economic reforms in Nigeria by the forces of
democracy in the country, the forces of globalisation have rendered these
reforms to be largely reactionary to domestic democratic forces. Invariably
therefore, the
41
weight of the forces of globalisation have
been responsible for the incapacitation of economic reforms in the advancement
of democratic lives in Nigeria.
To demonstrate this overall incapacitation of economic
reforms I have , even at the risk of repetition, categorised the reforms into
two. The first are those reforms whose orientations and implementations have
been shaped by the forces of globalisation in such a manner that their populist
democratic posturing has been undermined. The other are those economic reforms which have been directly enforced by
the forces of globalisation, particularly the World Bank, the IMF, the Paris
and London Clubs of creditors, with the objects of debt repayments, state
‘divestiture’ and market opening. In the category of the first are such
economic reforms in Nigeria as the Indigenisation and Nigerianisation Reforms;
Land Use Reform; and Poverty Alleviation Reforms. Included in the second
category are the Government Austerity Measures; Structural Adjustment
Programme; Privatisation and Commercialisation; National Economic Empowerment
and Development Strategy. Also included in this second category are the reforms
which have over the years been dealing with variations in exchange and interest
rates. These practices have received significant impetuses in the trade and
financial liberalisations under the aegis of neo-liberalism in Nigeria. The
trend here has geared mainly towards advancing the thrust of deregulations of
the political economy of Nigeria.
Despite this categorisation, it needs to be pointed out that
in the same manner that the forces of globalisation has continuously shaped the
creation and implementation of these reforms, domestic democratic forces have
continuously intruded into these practices. A clear instance here was the
creation of some populist programmes by the military regimes that implemented
SAP in order to stem the tide of massive anti-SAP riots in the 1980s and 1990s.
But, in the end, governance was neither stabilised nor were the people
effectively mobilised. Crisis and chaos took the greater part. Again, even when
certain elements of NEEDS had been designed to serve the Nigerian people, the
overall weakness of Nigeria in the global political economy has ensured that
more attention has still been paid to trade and market liberalisation. The
study advances to examine these specific reforms.
The Indigenisation and Nigerianisation Reforms in
Nigeria, 1960s, 1972, 1977 and Beyond
Ostensibly, the central objective of the
indigenisation reforms in Nigeria was the creation of an indigenous capitalist
class (Asobie 1988:48). The central elements of the policy included the
following:
42
• Increased
participation of Nigerians in the economic life of the country;
• Increased
capital accumulation by Nigerian businessmen and retention of such capital in
the country, and finally;
• Acquisition
by Nigerians of private entrepreneurial skills and orientation and capitalist
philosophy.
The reforms started with the Nigerian
Enterprises Promotion Decrees (1972, 1977) which have been amended over the
years.
Evidently, the indigenisation reforms were quite ramified
reforms for petty bourgeois economic nationalism in Nigeria. They owed their
genesis to the colonial era where the Nigerian petty bourgeois nationalist
leaders were excluded from the scheme of things by the European colonialists.
Indeed, the oligopoly which characterised European entrepreneurial activities
during colonialism stunted the growth of the Nigerian petty bourgeois class.
This trend was observable in commerce and in banking.
With enhanced local governance, one of the most immediate
concerns of the Nigerian nationalists was the creation of banks to liberalise
credits to the emerging African businessmen. Three such banks had been so
created for the three regions of Nigeria. The first was National Bank (Ltd) for
the Western Region. This was subsequently followed by African Continental Bank
(Ltd) for the Eastern Region and Bank of the North (Ltd) for the Northern
Region.
But the indigenisation reforms could not go as far as their
stated objectives tended to suggest. The Nigerian Enterprises Promotion Decree
of 1972 under Schedule 1 grouped exclusively for Nigerians and other Africans,
enterprises which required affordable capital investments. As has been rightly
observed,
...those were enterprises
which were already enjoying monopoly. These included: assembly of radios,
television sets, tape recorders and other electric domestic appliances not
combined with manufacture of components; blending and bottling of alcoholic
drinks; blocks; bricks; and ordinary tiles manufacture for building and
construction works; bread and cake making; candle manufacture; manufacture of
jewellery and related articles; ordinary garment manufacture not combined with
production of textile materials; rice milling; singlet manufacture and tyre
retreading. Others were: advertising agencies and public relations business;
radio and television broadcasting; newspaper publishing and printing; municipal
bus services and taxis; haulage of goods by roads; retail trade (except by or
within the departmental stores and supermarkets); clearing and forwarding
agencies; laundry and dry-cleaning; cinema and other places of entertainment;
casinos and gaming centres; and all aspects of pool betting and lotteries (FRN
1972:A20; FRN 2002:A19; FRN 2004:M10).
43
Given limited financial base of the emerging
Nigerian petty bourgeoisie and the fact that it latched on the public sector,
the peripheral roles which they have continued to play vis-à-vis their foreign counterparts is to be expected.
For instance, in all enterprises, foreign dominance for the years, 1971-75
ranged quite high. In 1971 and 1972, foreign ownership was 81.2 per cent and
83.4 per cent respectively. In 1972 foreign ownership in mining and quarrying
was as much as 98.3 per cent. Quite ominously related to this weak financial
base of the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie have been the eventual corrupt practices
which attended the utility of the banks which had been established to provide
credit. In Nigeria’s first republic, two premiers namely Dr. Nnamdi Azikiwe of
Eastern Region and Chief Obafemi Awolowo of Western Region were indicted for
using the funds of African Continental Bank (Ltd) and the National Bank (Ltd)
respectively to the benefit of the political parties which they controlled. In
any case, these banks all collapsed when Structural Adjustment Programme was
introduced in Nigeria.
There was also the Nigerianisation policy, a petty bourgeois
political accoutrement of the indigenisation reforms. This policy dates back to
the colonial era. According to the statement of policy of the Government of the
Federation on Nigerianisation of the public service presented to the Nigerian
parliament in 1965, the replacement of expatriates by Nigerians in the public
service was Nigeria’s number one policy priority. In the statement: the first
need of the Federation is for training a sufficient number of Nigerians to man
the whole of its public service.
Until the end of the World War II, the Nigerian higher
public service was an almost exclusive preserve of expatriates… by the middle
of 1948, there were in the senior service of the higher service of Nigeria
3,786 posts…only 245 (of these) posts were occupied by Africans
(Ejimofor,1987:141). When an enquiry into the Nigerianisation of the civil
service, conducted by Simeon Adebo and Sidney Phillipson in 1954 was made, it
had revealed overwhelming foreign domination of the roles in Nigeria’s civil
service. Out of a total of 559 senior service posts, 552 (or 93.4 per cent)
were occupied by expatriates. Only 37 (or 6.6 per cent) were occupied by
non-expatriates (Ekekwe 1986:46 in Asobie 1988:39).
Perhaps, the greatest problem of indigenisation reforms and
its Nigerianisation variant was not that it (especially the indigenisation
reforms) had been undermined by the forces of globalisation but mainly because
the reforms did not meaningfully address the problems of the masses of the
Nigerian people. Rather, the interest of the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie
dominated the reform protocols and their implementations. For even though the
Nigerian petty bourgeoisie mobilised the Nigerian people against colonial rule,
the limited democratic value of the emerging Nigerian state undermined
44
the effective representation of these people
in postcolonial governance. In any case, this mobilisation quickly dissipated
into ethnic identities thus undermining meaningful thrust of national
integration. The thirty-month Nigerian civil war and series of current
ethno-religious conflicts have been the most glaring manifestations of this
trend.
Nigeria’s Land Use Reform, 1978
The Land Use Decree of 1978 which later
became the Land Use Act of 1979 is another closely related reform for Nigerian
petty bourgeois economic sustenance. This Act vested all land comprised in the
territory of each State (except land vested in the Federal Government or its
agencies) solely in the Governor of the State, who would hold such land in
trust for the people and would henceforth be responsible for allocation of land
in all urban areas to individuals resident in the State and to organisations
for residential, agricultural, commercial and other purposes while similar
powers with respect to non-urban areas are conferred on Local Government Areas
(FMJ 2004:M10).
In vesting of land in the State, the Act stipulated that:
Subject to the provisions… all land comprised in the territory of each State of
the Federation is hereby vested on the Governor of that State, and such land
shall be held in trust and administered for the use and common benefit of all
Nigerians in accordance with the provisions of this Act.
The Act further provided that: There shall be established in
each State a body to be known as the Land Use and Allocation Committee which
shall have responsibility for the following:
• Advising
the Governor on any matter connected with the management of land…
• Advising
the Governor on any matter connected with the resettlement of persons affected
by the revocation of rights of occupancy on the ground of overriding public
interest under this Act; and;
• Determining
disputes as to the amount of compensation payable under this Act for the
improvements on land… (FMJ 2004).
The Act also made provisions for the
determination of what could be classified as urban lands. In the Act: subject
to such general conditions as may be specified on that behalf by the National
Council of States, the Governor may for the purposes of this Act by the order
published in the State Gazette designate the parts of the area of the territory
of the State constituted land in the urban area.
45
Nigeria’s land reform of 1978 made certain provisions with
regard to lands in the local government areas. According to the Act: it shall
be lawful for a local government in respect of land not in an urban area to:
• Grant
customary rights of occupancy to any person or organisation for the use of land
in the local government area for agricultural, residential and other purposes;
• Grant
customary rights of occupancy to any person or organisation for the use of land
for grazing purposes and such other purposes ancillary to agricultural purposes
as may be customary in the local government area concerned (FMJ 2004).
Evidently, the land reform in Nigeria whose
relevant provisions have been presented above was ostensibly designed to
address such issues as the dominance of peasant production relations in
agricultural productivity in Nigeria; the persistence of traditional land
tenure system in Nigeria and the nagging problems that have emerged in this
respect; as well as the irregularities in the development of the local
government system in the country.
The returns from the reform have nonetheless remained
shortchanged. Over years of programme implementation, rapid economic and social
changes in the country through efficient land use have remained a far cry.
Unwarranted land transactions, petty bourgeois land speculation among other
things have been limiting government roles in land management. Socioeconomic
inequalities engendered by traditional land ownership have given way to other
forms of inequalities namely those fostered by the emergent Nigerian nouveau
riche.
Invariably, the land reform was expected to transform the
structural practices in peasant dominated economic system to bourgeois
realities. The failure of this effort could be found in the fact that similar articulation
of social relations of production that are found in the economy equally
replicates at the level of political rule. Thus, by making a policy that seeks
to transform land ownership and control, the Nigerian state invariably
alienates the peasantry who above all depend on land as their principal means
of production. The peasantry in Nigeria also lacks the resources to compete for
land acquisition from the governments. What perhaps may have been achieved has
been some uneasy transformation of the peasantry into petty bourgeois existence
in which national development is still largely at risk.
Reforms for Poverty Alleviation in Nigeria,
2000-continuing
This is one of the economic reforms in
Nigeria that has apparently responded to popular struggles in the country. It
is important to point out from the
46
outset that Nigeria began to embark more
meaningfully in programmes of poverty alleviation only in the aftermath of the
excruciating but highly contested Structural Adjustment Programme in the
country.
The interest of the Nigerian state in poverty alleviation
was started with the Poverty Alleviation Programme (PAP) hurriedly put together
in the year 2000. In 2001, the programme was repackaged presumably for more
sustainable operations. It became the National Poverty Alleviation Programme
(NAPEP) with an enabling law and operational structure.
According to the programme
documentary, the thrust of NAPEP is to eradicate what it calls absolute
poverty. This according to them denotes a condition in which a person or group
of persons are unable to satisfy their most basic and elementary requirements of
human survival in terms of good nutrition, clothing, shelter, footwear,
transport, health, education, and recreation (NAPEP 2001:1).
But the important question to ask is how did
SAP become the precursor of the reforms for poverty alleviation in Nigeria? The
other question is what have been the inhibitions of the reforms for poverty
alleviation in Nigeria in routing the social problem of poverty in the
country? To begin with the first, it is
to be noted that, first and foremost, SAP unequivocally unleashed magnificent
pains on all social categories in the country thus requiring some balm. Second,
series of anti-SAP protests could definitely have informed the urgent need to
implement a social programme such as the poverty alleviation reforms.
One outstanding feature of SAP is that its pains never
really spared any domestic social force in Nigeria. In the volume, Dead-End to Nigerian Development, edited
by Professor Okwudiba Nnoli, satisfactory analyses of these conditions have
been presented.
In an apt summary of the contributions to the volume, the
book editor had noted that:
… the socioeconomic crisis which has faced
Nigeria since 1980 has given rise to an unprecedented rising level of
unemployment including amongst the most energetic, imaginative and highly
skilled; a growing poverty rate as reflected in low consumption levels, as well
as declining per capita income; a deteriorating standard of living of the mass
of the people; growing socioeconomic inequalities; and general insecurity of
lives and property. Inevitably, the underprivileged social groups have been the
ones most adversely affected. They include the peasants,… blue collar
workers,…petty artisans, craftsmen and traders; women and the youth… Apart from
these social categories, the petty bourgeoisie has also been adversely
affected… (Nnoli 1993:14).
These pains were equally met with resistance
by the Nigeria people. In 1989, for instance, there was a general strike
(popularly called the anti-SAP riot) that crippled social activities in the
entire federation.
47
The relatedness of SAP with the reforms for poverty
alleviation is clear enough. First and foremost, is that there have been policy
and programme contradictions between poverty alleviation reforms and the
equally gargantuan programmes of privatisation and commercialisation (the
latter unarguably rose in the wombs of SAP) both of which have been ongoing.
Second, despite huge expenditures and diversified attention, the success level
in the alleviation of poverty in Nigeria has been less than appreciable. The Daily Times of Nigeria edition of 20
June 2003 had noted that NAPEP gulped as much as N1.02 trillion over its years
of existence. The programme itself has been quite diversified involving 37 core
poverty alleviation institutions and 14 poverty alleviation ministries.
To further underscore its structural diversity, it is
instructive to note that its implementation stakeholders have included the
following: President of the Federal Republic of Nigeria, Vice- President,
Members of the National Assembly, Ministries and Agencies, Political Leaders,
Organised Private Sector, Labour Organisations, Chairmen of Local Government
Areas, Councillors, Traditional Rulers, Community Leaders, Community Based
Organisations (CBOs), Non-Governmental Organisations (NGOs), Extension
Officers, Women Group Leaders, Women Development Officers, and Local Government
Area Cooperative Officers. The related activities of NAPEP are equally
overwhelming. They include: Youth Empowerment Scheme (YES), Rural
Infrastructure Development Scheme (RIDS), Social Welfare Services Scheme
(SOWESS), and the Natural Resource Development and Conservation Scheme (NRDS).
The failures of the reforms for poverty alleviation have
been acknowledged. The current reports of the United Nations show that Human
Development Index (HDI) in Nigeria has remained less than 50 per cent which
places the country among the 25 poorest countries in the world. This is in
addition to Nigeria’s life expectancy at birth which stands at 48 years,
literacy rate was placed at 44 per cent
and 70 per cent of the rural population
do not have access to potable water, healthcare facilities and electricity.
In a review of the implementation of NEEDS between 2004 and
2007, the implementers have been modest enough to admit that:
…not much seems to have been
achieved with respect to efforts aimed at reducing extreme poverty and hunger,
reduction in child mortality, and maternal health, general containment of
HIV/AIDS-related goals, and environmental sustainability…It appears the nation
needs to intensify her efforts towards meeting these goals, without which the
poverty alleviation objectives of NEEDS may not be realised (NPC 2008:20).
These views are in consonance with the data
from the Millennium Development Goals implementation which show that the
population of
48
Nigerians living in relative poverty moved
from 43 per cent in 1992 to 66 per cent in 1996. By 2004 and 2005 the figure
hovers around 54 per cent. And yet the target for 2015 is 21 per cent. Despite
insufficient data, it has been gleaned that the population of Nigerians living
in extreme poverty (i.e., those consuming 2,900 calories or lower daily)
constitute 35 per cent for both 2004 and 2005. Also the population of
underweight Nigerians under five years of age amount to 30 per cent for both
2004 and 2005.
Again, the explanation for these realities is that the
reforms for poverty alleviation have been massively enhancing the development
of the Nigerian petty bourgeoisie, the most privileged class in the Nigerian
domestic political economy. The weakness of this class in the private sector, a
testimony of the comprador character of the Nigerian political economy has made
its perpetuation in the public sector a problem for poverty alleviation
reforms. Moreover, the reforms have been facilitating brain drain.
Government Austerity Measures, 1982-84
The economic reform package popularly called
government austerity measures represented a stop-gap between the overt petty
bourgeois economic nationalism of the 1960s and the 1970s and the
all-encompassing SAP of the mid-1980s and beyond. Indeed, the stringent
macroeconomic programmes embodied in the austerity measures had been blamed on
the profligacy of the antecedent reforms for petty bourgeois economic
nationalism.
Evidently, the austerity measures were policy responses to
the mounting external debt crisis which Nigeria began to experience mostly as
from the latter part of the 1970s. While the remote course is attributable to
the comprador and peripheral character of the Nigerian political economy, the
immediate causes were the debt bunching arising from the maturity of soft loans
granted particularly by the IBRD and other bilateral sources especially in the
early years of independence. Other causes include the limited capacity of the
‘oil boom’ of the mid-1970s to advance national development resulting in the
thrust of external borrowing even while oil flowed; the expansion of the
sources of external foreign loans to include the highly costly EuroDollar
capital market and, of course the raising of the huge US$1 billion Euro-Dollar
loan in January 1978; and finally inefficiency and corruption in the country’s
public sector.
With the coming into being of the World Bank Accelerated
Development in sub-Saharan Africa popularly known as the Berg Report in 1981,
the IMF began to pressure these countries over questions of national
development especially over the issue of huge external indebtedness. The Berg
Report
49
focused on what it described as over-valued
national currencies, neglect of peasant agriculture, heavily protected
manufacturing sector, and excessive government intervention in the economy
(Cheru 1989:9-10). African leaders on their part insisted that the
developmental malaise of the period were created by variations in the interest
rates and other such financial manipulations by the advanced countries.
This particular face-off became obvious in the loan
negotiations between Nigeria and the IMF in the 1980s. Owing to some
disagreements, the Federal Government of Nigeria enunciated the Economic
Stabilisation (Temporary Provision) Act of 1981. This Act introduced the
austerity measures in Nigeria. Indeed, the Act:
targeted the manifest
excesses in government spending and tried to curb the persistent deficit in the
balance of payments through stringent import and exchange rate controls. The
fiscal retrenchment consisted of a freeze on capital expenditure, the
curtailment of low-priority public investment projects, an increase in
petroleum product prices and utility tariffs, a freeze on wages and salaries in
the public sector, and a restriction of foreign borrowing by state and local
governments (Herbst and Soludo 2001:661).
The
idea appeared to be that of curbing rising extravagance which had been further
induced by the ‘oil boom’ and, by so doing, save foreign exchange earnings.
The specific provisions of the
Act included: the limiting of foreign exchange disbursements for imports and
other international transactions from N1.2 billion per month during the first
quarter of 1982 to N800.00 million subsequently. Basic Travel Allowance was
also reduced from N800.00 per annum to N500.00 while Business Travel Allowance
was reduced from N3000.00 to N2500.00. This Act also provided for immediate
closure of all private jetties in the country and a decrease in petroleum
subsidy which resulted in 5 kobo per litre rise in pump price among others
(see, for instance, Aribisala 1987:11).
Buoyed by the Berg Report, the IMF was not
impressed with the austerity measures of Nigeria. It insisted on a fundamental
liberalisation of the domestic political economy. After a few years of
prevarications occasioned also by two military coups d’état, the Structural
Adjustment Programme was introduced in Nigeria in 1986. It needs only to be noted that during the
period of austerity measures, basic household items in Nigeria including especially
rice, milk and toiletries had been classified as ‘essential commodities’ which
meant that they had already gone beyond the reach of most Nigerians and were
only distributed piecemeal by the government.
The Reforms of Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP),
1986-93
Perhaps what sets out the reforms of the SAP
may not necessarily be that they have been the most wide ranging of all major
economic reform protocols
50
across the globe, nor even the least
surprising that their implementations unleashed near-undiscriminatory pains on
all domestic social forces in the country. The high point of the reforms in
this regard may really be that, so far, it was the first reform protocol that
had been most directly imposed by the Bretton Woods institutions and their
related bodies without due regards whatsoever to the often noticed
collaborations between these institutions and the dominant domestic social
forces in these political economies that had to be adjusted.
The above statement is pungent enough but easily
understandable especially when the Nigerian situation is put in sharp focus. It
is pungent enough because both the IMF and the governing circles in the
sub-Saharan African countries (where the Nigerian-type package had been
uniformly applied) were fully reflective of the problems of the SAP therapy and
sharply disagreed over it. Indeed, it took close to half a decade between the
time that the Berg Report recommended SAP in 1981 and the time that the various
sub-Saharan African countries including Nigeria finally succumbed to its
adoption. For Nigeria, for instance, it took five years, the toppling of an
elected civilian administration and a counter coup for the programme to take
off. It was nonetheless understandable because as it has become quite clear,
SAP was introduced in response to the uncompromising pressures of creditor
agencies. It was only incidental that these pressures needed to rub off on all
the domestic social forces in the countries, including especially the domestic
governing circles.
The implementers of Nigeria’s SAP suggested that it had the
following objectives:
• Restructuring
and diversifying the productive base of the economy in order to reduce its
dependence on the oil sector and on imports;
• Achieving
in the short- to medium-term fiscal and balance of payments viability;
• Laying
the basis for a sustainable non-inflationary growth; and
• Reducing
the dominance of unproductive investments in the public sector, improving that
sector’s efficiency and enhancing the potential of the private sector.
For the implementers, the main instruments
for achieving these objectives,
was to alter the system of
determining the exchange rate of the domestic currency by replacing the
previous fixed exchange rate system with an open bidding system…The other key
instruments that were adopted under the SAP included progressive trade and
payments liberalisation, adoption of appropriate pricing policies for public
enterprises and rationalisation (i.e., commercialisation/ privatisation) of
public sector enterprises; reduction of government deficit financing
51
and pursuit of tight monetary
and fiscal policies to counter the inherent inflationary pressures that
accompany currency depreciation in the short term (FRN 1990:34).
Understandably, the adoption of SAP by
Nigeria opened the doors for official external debt rescheduling. Three debt
rescheduling agreements with the Paris Club had been made: a 1986 agreement
that rescheduled/refinanced debt worth about US$4.6 billion; a 1989 agreement
that rescheduled about US$5.2 billion; and a 1991 agreement that rescheduled
about US$3.3 billion (Ikem 1996 in Herbst and Soludo 2001:667).
As events have proven, SAP was the wrong recipe for
resolving the developmental lacuna of Nigeria. In particular, the comprador and
peripheral character of the Nigerian political economy could not be reversed by
SAP. It wrought poverty on the Nigerian population. ‘Composite price index for
all items rose from 484 in 1985 to 550 in 1987. In 1988, it rose even further
to 850. The rate of inflation rose from 5 to 50 per cent between 1987 and 1989’
(Asobie 1993:189). Nigeria’s debt crisis even worsened with SAP. ‘Its total
debt figure experienced a phenomenal growth from N5, 7289.8 million in 1985 to
N381,987.4 million in 1990. The total debt stock for 1995 was N1, 057,857.9
million representing an increase of 63.3 per cent over the value for 1990.
Against the critical debt ratios, the debt burden became heavier for Nigeria
due to SAP’ (Umezurike 2004:23).
Nigeria’s SAP also created political upheavals in the
country. In May 1988, Nigerian workers embarked on a nation-wide industrial
action which spilled over to the anti-SAP riots of 1989. The latter embraced
students and other urban dwellers. Providers of public utilities including the
defunct National Electric Power Authority were equally involved. The Federal
Government reacted by placing bans on the activities of the Nigerian Labour
Congress (NLC) in 1988. In the inflexible attitude of the military, other
organised labour including the Academic Staff Union of Universities (ASUU), and
the Nigerian Medical Association (NMA) were at one time or the other arm twisted.
Dismissal of university lecturers became rampant at this time as university
students were murdered in cold blood in their university campuses.
Nigeria’s continued dependence on crude petroleum in spite
of SAP continued to pitch its governments against oil and environmental
activists. The military regime of late General Sani Abacha did not hesitate to
hang nine of such activists, including the writer, Ken Saro Wiwa.
Reforms of Privatisation and Commercialisation,
1980s, 1990s-continuing
The policy measures of privatisation and
commercialisation have been responses to some conjectural issues bordering on
the limitations of
52
democratic governance in Nigeria. One of
these issues is the inefficiency and ineffectiveness in public governance which
have been vivid in the activities of public corporations in the country.
Another has been rampant corruption in the country’s public sector. Also
notable is the related limited accountability of public officials including
those of public parastatals. Equally important has been the declining values of
governance owing to political instability. Finally, there were pressures from
foreign creditor agencies on the Nigerian governments to reduce the size and
roles of the public sector.
Invariably, attempts to legitimise the programmes of
privatisation and commercialisation have in themselves turned out to be
indictments on poor democratic governance in the country. For instance, to
initiate one of the programmes, it had once been pointed out that:
it is estimated that successive Nigerian
Governments have invested up to N8000 billion in public-owned enterprises.
Annual returns on this huge investment have been well below 10 per cent. These
inefficiencies and, in many cases huge losses, are charged against the public
treasury. With declining revenue and escalating demand for effective and
affordable social services, the general public has stepped up its yearning for
state-owned enterprises to become more efficient (FRN 2000:4).
In 1998 alone, government sources noted that
Public Enterprises in Nigeria had enjoyed the following transfers: N156.5
billion subsidised foreign exchange; N12.5 billion imported heavy waivers;
N15.0 billion tax exemption arrears; N29.5 billion unremitted revenues; N16.5
billion loans and guarantees and N35.0 billion grants and subventions. Also
these sources reveal that over US$100 billion had been sunk on the Public
Enterprises in Nigeria between 1975 and 1995. In 1999, the sources continue,
there was a total of 590 Public Enterprises at the Federal level all of which
gave over 5000 Board appointments.
A precursor to privatisation and commercialisation was
experienced during austerity measures when the General Buhari administration,
apparently in response to the stringent crisis of the Nigerian political economy,
curtailed the funding of public parastatals and also withdrew subsidies to a
number of products of these parastatals. These trends continued until 1988 when
the first privatisation and commercialisation programme in Nigeria commenced.
The commencement of the programme was marked by Decree No. 25 of 1988. This
Decree set up the Technical Committee on Privatisation and Commercialisation
(TCPC) with government mandate for managing the exercise. Expectedly, this
mandate was in line with the requirements of SAP which had been barely two
years old then.
The stated objectives of the Committee, as contained in the
Decree, included the following:
53
• Restructuring
and rationalising the public sector in order to lessen the dominance of
unproductive investment in that sector;
• Reorientation
of the enterprises for privatisation and commercialisation towards a new
horizon of performance improvement, viability and overall efficiency;
• Ensuring
positive returns on public sector investment in commercialised enterprises;
• Checking
the present absolute dependence on the treasury for funding the otherwise
commercially oriented parastatals and to encourage their approach to the
Nigerian capital market; and finally,
• Initiating
the process of gradual ceding to the private sector of such public enterprises
which by nature and type of operations are best performed by the private
sector.
At the termination of this first exercise,
out of the 110 enterprises slated for privatisation, and 34 others for
commercialisation, 82 of them were actually privatised. There were a total of
1.5 billion shares sold, 280 board seats ceded by the Federal Government and a
reduction of treasury funding. Also, N3.7 billion was raised from the exercise.
A total of 800, 000 new shareholders were created with the emergence of
shareholders association. This first experience however ended in 1993.
The second experience of the programmes was initiated by the
first post-military regime of President Olusegun Obasanjo. Similarly, this was
consummated in a legal framework tagged: Public Enterprises (Privatisation and
Commercialisation) Act of 1999. It is nonetheless instructive to note that this
second experience had similar objectives with the previous. Identified
differences could only be that of emphasis of its avowed state-sanitisation
endeavours. For instance, parts of these objectives were to:
• Send
a clear message to local and international community that a new transparent
Nigeria is open for business;
• Raise
funds for financing socially oriented (poverty alleviation, health, education,
etc) programmes.
The unbridled pursuit of the programmes by
the Obasanjo regime was clearly not in doubt. As indicated above, the Technical
Committee on Privatisation and Commercialisation (TCPC) metamorphosed into the
Bureau for Public Enterprises with the enabling laws. It had equally been noted
that the second experience saw the privatisation and commercialisation of far
bigger enterprises than the first.
54
But it is also important to explain that the post-military
regime of President Obasanjo equally underscored the clear global implications
of the exercises. As the President indicated in one of his speeches:
…there are overwhelming facts and figures in
support of the absolute necessity to realign ourselves with these global
trends…Privatisation is one of the reforms we have to undertake to integrate
our economy into the mainstream of world economic order. There are two
interrelated aspects to this integration. In the first place, we need the
technology; the managerial competence and the capital from the developed world
to enhance the performance of our utilities. Second, there are very serious
linkages between the efficient functioning of our utilities and our ability to
attract foreign investments. We cannot be talking about creating a conducive
environment for foreign investments if the performance of our transport,
telecommunication, and energy sectors remains dismal and epileptic (FRN
2000:5).
Reforms of the National Economic Empowerment and
Development Strategy (NEEDS), 2004-2007
The framers of the NEEDS programme have
failed to give it one precise definition. They have described it in a number of
forms. First, it has been described as Nigeria’s plan for prosperity. Second,
it has been described as the people’s way of letting the government know what
kind of Nigeria they wish to live in, now and in future. Third, it has also
been described by the same framers as the government’s way of letting the
people know how it plans to overcome the deep and pervasive obstacles to
progress that the government and the people have identified. The fourth and
final description given by this source is that it is also a way of letting the
international community know where Nigeria stands – in the region and in the
world – and how it wishes to be supported.
The NEEDS framers claim that the process began in 2001 when
people from all walks of life and all parts of Nigeria were given the chance to
tell the government about their needs and ambitions. Information collected from
farmers, labourers, factory owners, teachers and university professors,
community-based organisations, charities and other stakeholders was used to
draft an interim Poverty Reduction Paper. But its public presentation in the
year 2004 put forward the following macroeconomic reform framework:
right-sizing of the public sector; restructuring of the various departments
within each ministry of government;
monetisation of fringe benefits; reform of pension scheme; introduction
of due process; intensified privatisation and commercialisation of public
enterprises; establishment of anti-corruption institutions; reform of the
telecommunication and energy sectors; extensive reform of the financial sector,
especially the re-capitalisation of the banking
55
and insurance institutions; liquidation of a
very large proportion of the nation’s external debt. And finally, reform of the
judiciary, among others.
What is clear is that NEEDS has incorporated certain
tendencies in Nigeria’s political governance which do not necessarily
invalidate the argument that it is a carry-over from the erstwhile SAP but does
obviate the fact that the framers of NEEDS benefited from the experiences of
SAP implementers. A proof of this is already evident in the reforms for poverty
alleviation which forms part of the NEEDS package. The framers of NEEDS also created such
anti-corruption institutions as the Code of Conduct Bureau, Economic and
Financial Crimes Commission (EFCC) and the Independent Corruption (and related)
Practices Commission (ICPC).
Indeed, the NEEDS framework provided for a number of what
have been referred to as Core Economic Reform Programme initiated by the
President Obasanjo regime. According to the regime, some of the objectives of
these programme have included: transparency of oil and gas accounts; demonstration
of the negative consequences of economic crimes; demonstration of Nigeria’s
willingness to fight money laundering, show value for money and transparency in
government contracting; improvement of fiscal discipline at all tiers of
government, and so on.
Much of these state-sanitising projects of NEEDS have
unarguably been government propaganda and have characteristically failed at
implementation. What is important about them however is that they have
represented the disgust of Nigerians about public governance especially under
the SAP regime. Moreover, heavy involvement of retired senior military officers
in the President Obasanjo regime appeared to have incorporated the relevance of
sanitising Nigeria’s public sector. Social degeneration of that sector,
especially under the SAP regime, almost crippled the military institution
itself.
Trade and Financial Liberalisations, Especially
under the SAP and Post-SAP Regimes
Trade and financial liberalisations
especially since the SAP and post-SAP regimes have been gargantuan. As Black
(2002) has observed, trade liberalisation has meant ‘the process of reducing or
removing restrictions on international trade’ (Black 2002:471). On the other
hand, financial deregulation has been shown to depict:
the removal or relaxation of
regulations affecting the type of business financial firms may undertake, the
type of firms permitted to deal in particular markets, or the terms on which
dealing is allowed…Regulations which have been relaxed include controls on the
interest rates at which banks can lend or borrow, controls on operations by
banks outside their country of registration, and restrictions on the types of
business particular financial institutions can transact (Black 2002:174).
56
Export-led developmental strategy which had
been strengthened in the regime of Nigeria’s neo-liberal reforms terminated the
era of import substitution industries which had anchored national development
since about 1946. The termination also engendered a condition in which the laws
of demand and supply ruled the thrust of foreign trade in the country. In this
context, the country became strongly disadvantaged as its export products were
minimal and depended mainly on agricultural products in which it even has low
competitive advantage in the international market. Thus apart from crude
petroleum which has dominated its exports over the years, it has concentrated
on meagre re-exports of some manufactures. In the same vein, neo-liberal regime
in Nigeria has created unsettling moments in the management of interest rates
as the banking system has lacked adequate stability.
At the earliest periods of the neo-liberal reforms as from
the latter part of the 1980s, Nigerian governments created foreign exchange
markets which replaced the earlier use of import licences for transactions
abroad. In the most recent past, there has been official permission for the
sale of foreign currencies by banks and bureau de change outfits. The prices of
foreign currencies, including especially the dollar, pound sterling, euro, yen,
etc., have been floated against the determining forces of the market. Even
though some stability has been observed especially with regard to the major
currencies for over half a decade now, there is certainly something to worry
about the low value of the Nigerian naira against these currencies over these
years of neo-liberal reforms. For instance, at the earliest periods of
political independence, the Nigerian currency had been officially pegged at par
with the British pound sterling. The Nigerian naira was actually officially
exchanged at about N0.66 to US$1 in 1978
when the country raised a jumbo loan from the Euro-Dollar capital market; but
is currently exchanged at the range of N153.00 to US$1.00.
In addition to the above, the country has depended almost
exclusively on crude petroleum for foreign exchange. For instance, in 1987, oil
exports were N28,154.4 million while non-oil exports were N1,423.6 million; in
a year in which domestic exports had been N29,577.94 million. Similar trends
repeated themselves in 2005 and 2006. For 2005, oil exports had been as much as
N6,252,882.3 million while non-oil exports had been mere N368,421.4million. For
2006, oil exports rose to N7,006,591.1million as against non-oil exports of
N548,550.2 million. The domestic exports and re-exports for the years 2005 and
2006 were N6,621,303.64 million and N7,555,141.32 million respectively. The
incapacitation of the ongoing neoliberal reforms in Nigeria to diversify the
economy largely explain the heavy dependence on oil for foreign earnings.
57
Despite current thrust in risk management by the Central
Bank of Nigeria especially in response to the global financial meltdown, the
banking sector in Nigeria has not quite resonated the agenda of development in
the neo-liberal conjuncture. Corruption has been rife in the banks and despite
numerous efforts at recapitalisation among other reforms, a number of these
banks have not fared satisfactorily:
As at 2006, a total of 25
banks in Nigeria had been capitalised to the tune of N866.40 billion. But in
August 2009, the new Central Bank Governor Mallam Sanusi Lamido Sanusi who
replaced Professor Charles Soludo had made public a crisis in these banks. A
number of Chief Executives of these banks lost their jobs while government
bail-out measures had been resumed (Umezurike 2010:90).
Not too long after, that is in 2011, three
of the banks that had been recapitalised namely Bank PHB Ltd, Afribank Bank PLC
and Spring Bank PLC, became liquidated by the Asset Management Company of
Nigeria AMCON, an outfit that had been created by the Central Bank of Nigeria
for risk management purposes. Three other new banks were created by AMCON to
replace them.
On a general note, however, Nigerian banks have continued to
create lesser impetus for advancing national development. Despite the infusion
of new facilities and innovations, Nigerians, especially in rural settings are
yet to grasp their relevance. Credit facilities have still remained a
prerogative of the elites.
Conclusion
The study sustains the thesis that through
economic reforms in Nigeria, the forces of globalisation have been negating
democracy in the country. The impetus for this thesis has arisen from the need
to explore this ominous relationship between globalisation and democracy in
Nigeria as in much of Africa beyond the massive intellectual outpouring on the
Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) foisted by the IMF on the sub-Saharan
African countries in the 1980s and 1990s. Even though the negative implications
of SAP for development in Nigeria as in the rest of Africa have been examined,
this study notes that economic reforms generally have been largely volatile and
contradictory that it requires a compendium of these reforms to properly
problematise their implications for democracy in Nigeria for instance. The core
undercurrent of SAP is the unbridled advancement of market liberalisation and
state ‘divestiture’. The continuation of this core thrust in the other
similarly related programmes such as the current National Economic Empowerment
and Development Strategy (NEEDS) has been significantly affected not only by
the volatility and contradictions of global market forces but also by the
thrust of domestic social struggles. In any case, the reforms
58
for Indigenisation and Nigerianisation which
preceded SAP had pursued economic nationalism of the Nigerian governing elites
which had not been directly related to the thrust of market liberalisation and
state ‘divestiture’.
The significance of this paper, therefore, is not only in
the exploration of the negative relationship between globalisation and
democracy in Nigeria but recognition of the significant character and
implications of economic reform as the intervening variable. In doing so, it
has been suggested that knowledge production on economic reform should not be limited
to market liberalisation as its global practices have been interpreted. Rather,
economic reform should represent also government policies on the economy that
reproduces domestic democratic struggles. Failure to recognise the roles of
domestic social forces in inducing economic reforms in Nigeria, for instance,
is inadequate not only for understanding these reforms but also for properly
situating the possible courses of history in contemporary globalisation.
The study shows that there are similarities in the intensity
and character of global negation of democracy in Nigeria on the one hand, and
the convergence of economic reform protocols and the forces of globalisation on
the other hand. These similarities are more easily provable in the economic reforms
embodied in the Austerity Measures of the early 1980s; the SAP of 1980s and
1990s; the reforms of Privatisation and Commercialisation as from the 1980s;
the current NEEDS as well as the liberalisations of trade and finance which
have had some impetuses for interest and exchange rate regimes under
deregulation. Here, the thrusts of market liberalisation and state
‘divestiture’ have been much more emphasised. On the other hand, the reforms
for Poverty Alleviation as from 2001; Indigenisation and Nigerianisation in the
1960s and 1970s; and Land Use in the 1970s, have largely reproduced the
inadequacies of the Nigerian governing circles in advancing the democratic
struggles of the Nigerian people. Thus the reforms have in this respect been
reactionary to domestic social struggles.
The incongruity of the forces of globalisation and domestic
democratic forces in Nigeria, as has been effectively orchestrated by the
practices of economic reforms in the country, requires urgent global attention.
This is even more so now that economic reform remains the most significant
thrust of public policy in the developing countries.
References
Aaron,
K.K., 2001, ‘Playing Without Kits: Towards a Beneficial Participation of Africa
in a Globalized World’, Annals of the
Social Science Academy of Nigeria13, pp.1-15.
Adejumobi,
S., 2004, ‘Economic Globalization, Market Reforms and Social Welfare Services
in West Africa’, in Aina, T. A., Chachage,
Seithy, Chachage, L. and
59
Annan-Yao, Elisabeth, eds, Globalization and Social Policy in Africa, Dakar:
CODESRIA.
Ake, Claude, 1985, Political Economy of Nigeria, London:
Longman.
Ake, Claude, 2003, The Feasibility of Democracy in Africa,
Dakar: CODESRIA.
Amin, S.,
1990, Maldevelopment: Anatomy of Global
Failure, London, NJ, and Zed Books.
Amin, S., 1998, Capitalism in the Age of Globalization,
London: Zed Books.
Anstey, R.,
1975, The Atlantic Slave Trade and
British Abolition, London: Macmillan.
Aribisala, F., 1987 ‘The History of Austerity Measures
in Contemporary Nigeria, 1914-84’, in Ofomata, G.E.K. and Ikpeze, N., eds, Austerity and the Nigerian Society,
Onitsha: Etukokwu.
Austen, R.,
1987, African Economic History: Internal
Development and External Dependence, London: James Currey.
Asobie,
H.A., 1988, ‘Indigenization, Class Formation and Class Struggles in Nigeria: An
Analysis’, Africa Development XII(2).
Asobie,
H.A., 2001, ‘Globalization: A View from the South’, Annals of the Social Science Academy of Nigeria 13.
Black, J.,
2002, Oxford Dictionary of Economics,
2nd edition, Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.
Blomstrom,
M. and Lundahl, M., eds, 1993, Economic
Crisis in Africa: Perspectives on Policy Responses, London and New York:
Routledge.
Central
Bank of Nigeria, various issues, Annual
Reports and Statement of Accounts, Lagos and Abuja: CBN.
Central
Bank of Nigeria, various issues, Economic
and Financial Review, Lagos and Abuja: CBN.
Cheru, F.,
1989, The Silent Revolution in Africa:
Debt, Development and Democracy, Harare and London: Anvil and Zed Books.
Ejimofor,
C.O., 1987, British Colonial Objectives
and Policies in Nigeria: The Roots of Conflict, Onitsha: Africana-Feb.
Federal Ministry of Information, 1978,
Decree No. 6, The Land Use Decree 1978. Federal
Ministry of Justice, 2002, Laws of the
Federation of Nigeria, Vol.14, A19. Federal Ministry of Justice, 2004, Laws of the Federation of Nigeria, Vol.
18, M10. Federal Republic of Nigeria, 1972, Laws
of the Federal Republic of Nigeria, p. 20.
Federal
Republic of Nigeria, 1990, First National
Rolling Plan, Lagos: Planning Office, Federal Ministry of Budget and
Planning.
Federal
Republic of Nigeria, 2000, Privatization
Handbook, 2nd edition, Abuja: FRN.
Gibbon, P., ed, 1993, Social Change and Economic Reform in Africa,
Uppsala: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet, The Scandinavian Institute of African
Studies.
Gibbon, P.
and Ponte, S., 2005, Trading Down:
Africa, Values Gains, and the Global Economy, Philadelphia: Temple
University Press.
60
Herbst, J.
and Soludo, C. C., 2001, ‘Nigeria’, in Shantayanan, D. et al., eds, Aid and Reforms in Africa: Lessons from Ten
Case Studies, Washington D.C.: The World Bank.
Ibeanu,
O.O. and Egwu, S., 2007, Popular
Perceptions of Democracy and Political Governance in Nigeria. London,
Abuja: Centre for Democracy and Development.
Keller, W.W. and Pauly, L. W.,
1997, ‘Globalization at Bay’, Current
History96 (613). Khor, M., 2001, Globalization
and the South: Some Critical Issues, Ibadan: Spectrum Books.
Mander, J.
and Goldsmith, E., eds, 1996, The Case
Against Global Economy and A Turn Towards the Local, San Francisco: Sierra
Club Books.
National
Bureau for Statistics, various issues, Annual
Abstract of Statistics, Abuja: NBS.
National
Centre for Economic Management and Administration, 2004, ‘Understanding
Structural Adjustment Programme in Nigeria’, Paper presented at the Workshop on
Understanding Reform, New Delhi.
National Planning Commission, 2004,
Meeting Everybody’s NEEDS, Abuja:
NPC.
National
Planning Commission, 2005, National
Economic Empowerment Development Strategy, (NEEDS), Abuja: NPC.
National
Planning Commission, 2008, Review of
Implementation of NEEDS, 20042007, Abuja: NPC.
National
Poverty Eradication Programme, 2000, Concepts,
Implementation, Coordination and Monitoring, Abuja: NPC.
National
Poverty Eradication Programme, 2001, A
Blueprint for the Programmes, Abuja.
Ndiaye, A.I., 2004, ‘Economic
Reforms and Social Policies in Senegal’, in Aina, T. A. et. al, eds, Globalization and Social Policies in Africa,
Dakar: CODESRIA. Nnoli, O., ed,1981, Path
to Nigerian Development, Dakar: CODESRIA.
Nnoli, O.,
ed, 1993, Dead-End to Nigerian
Development: An Investigation on the Social, Economic and Political Crisis in
Nigeria, Dakar: CODESRIA.
Offiong,
D.A., 2001, Globalization,
Post-Neocolonialism and Poverty in Africa, Enugu: Fourth Dimension
Publishers.
Olukoshi,
A. ed.1993, The Politics of Structural
Adjustment in Nigeria, London, James Currey and Heinemann.
Onimode, B.
1992, A Future for Africa: Beyond the
Politics of Adjustment, London: Earthscan Publications.
Rosenau,
J.N. 1997, ‘The Complexities and Contradictions of Globalization’, Current History 96 (613).
Shaw, T.M.,
1993, Reformism and Revisionism in
Africa’s Political Economy in the 1990s: The Dialectics of Adjustment,
London: The Macmillan Press.
Strange, S., 1997, ‘The
Erosion of the State’, Current History
96 (613). Tarp, F., 1993, Stabilization
and Structural Adjustment: Macroeconomic Framework for Analyzing the Crisis in
Sub-Saharan Africa, London and New York: Routledge.
61
Turner, T.,
1981, ‘Nigeria: Imperialism, Oil Technology and the Comprador State’, in Nore,
P. and Turner, T., eds, Oil and Class
Struggle, London: Zed Press.
Umezurike,
C., 2004, ‘Poverty Reduction and Development in Nigeria: A Political Economy
Approach’ Nigerian Journal of Politics
and Administration 2 (1).
Umezurike,
C., 2006, ‘Economic Reforms and Democratization in Nigeria: A Historical
Overview’, Paper presented at the Annual Conference of the Nigerian Political
Science Association held at the University of Port Harcourt, November.
Umezurike,
C., 2008, ‘Globalization and Labour in
Africa: Ethnic Identity in Nigeria, Cross Border Migration in the Republic of
South Africa’, Globalizations5(4),
pp. 599-619.
Umezurike,
C., 2010, State and Economy in Nigeria: A
Study of Democracy and Economic Reforms in the Fourth Republic, Enugu:
SNAAP Press Ltd.
Umezurike,
C. and Eboh, E., 1993, ‘The Reform of Parastatals Enterprises in Nigeria’,
Research Paper submitted to the West African Economic Association, Abidjan.
Umezurike,
C.and Eboh, E., 1993, ‘The Reform of Parastatals Enterprises in Nigeria’,
Research paper submitted to the West African Economic Association, Abidjan.
Umezurike,
C., Aruah, E. O. and Eboh, E., 1996, ‘The Reform of Public Enterprises in
Nigeria: A Case Study of Anambra-Imo River Basin Development Authority’, Working paper (19), NISER/SSCN National
Research Network on Liberalization Policies in Nigeria, supported by the
International Development Research Center, Canada.
World Bank,
1981, Accelerated Development in
Sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for Action, Washington, D. C.: World Bank.
No comments:
Post a Comment