The implication of the Soskice model is that the more
coordinated a market economy is, the more likely it will be to internalize
demands for greater stimulus. I will test this hypothesis against three
alternative theories. First, while institutions are important, it is not the
VoC institutions that matter so much as fiscal institutions. A series of
studies have sought to show how and what kinds of rules can restrict the
choices that politicians can make when it comes to public spending and
taxation, including executive flexibility, amendment powers, access to
information, and so forth (Hallerberg et al., 2001; von Hagen, 1992; 2003; von
Hagen & Harden, 1994; Wehner, 2006). Hence, more restrictive budgetary
institutions could dampen stimulus measures.
Another possibility is that governments’ concerns with debt
credibility will limit the extent of discretionary fiscal stimulus. The logic
here is that, for fiscal expansion to generate economic growth, bond markets
need to be confident that governments will fulfill their financial obligations.
Discretionary fiscal stimulus expands governments’ commitments to domestic and
international creditors through its increased stress on budgets and total
government debt, while potentially signaling excessive liabilities to bond
markets. This hypothesis follows from David Cameron’s (2012) argument that
budgetary constraint was the primary predictor of fiscal stimulus size during
these time periods.
Finally, there is the question of party politics. Following
Hibbs (1977), an immense body of scholarship has examined the expectation that
partisan politics matters for understanding a variety of policy outcomes,
including budgetary expansion/contraction and welfare state
retrenchment/maintenance (see, e.g., Breunig, 2011; Breunig & Busemeyer,
2014; Jensen & Mortensen, 2014; Cusack, 1997; Jensen, 2010). Recent studies
have suggested that the impact of party politics in understanding fiscal policy
in response to recession (Armingeon, 2012; Raess & Pontusson, 2015) is
limited.
Left parties are assumed to push for lower unemployment,
higher social spending, and greater income equality. The expectation here is
that greater left party power will propel governments to enact greater stimulus
measures. For the dependent variable, I use OECD data on the magnitude of
discretionary fiscal stimulus measures—total combination of tax cuts and
spending increases— between 2008 and 2010, as a percentage of 2008 GDP (OECD,
2010). The values of this variable are positive for stimuli and negative for
adjustment. This measurement excludes automatic stabilizers and avoids post hoc
assessments of stimulus, like its effects on economic growth, government debt,
inequality, and so forth.
For the VoC variable, the principal indicator is the degree
of institutional coordination. Institutional coordination constitutes the
degree to which firms in a production regime are empowered by the institutional
complementarities in which they are embedded. Although different measurements
of coordination exist in the literature, I use Knell and Srholec’s (2007)
coordination index (KS hereafter). Inspired by a working paper version of Hall
and Gingerich’s (2009) use of factor analysis to build a quantitative
measurement of coordination, KS consists of an additive index, constructed from
the results of factor analysis loadings for social cohesion, labor market
regulation, and business regulation.1 KS has several advantages over Hall and
Gingerich’s (2009) index. First, it uses more recent data. Second, while Hall
and Gingerich use 20 OECD countries for their factor analysis, KS uses 51
countries, which make their factor loadings more plausible. Third, KS includes
several East European and non-European countries for comparative purposes, some
of which are used in the current analysis.
To test the fiscal institutions hypothesis, I use Wehner’s
(2006) index of legislative budget institutions. This index comprises six
institutional prerequisites for legislative control: amendment powers,
reversionary budgets, executive flexibility during budget execution, the timing
of the budget, legislative committees, and budgetary information. All data is
from a 2003 OECD–World Bank collaborative survey of specially identified
budgetary officials in 36 countries, including all but 2 of the countries in
the current study (see Wehner, 1 For each of these three composites, there are
four variables, as follows: for social cohesion, inequality, marginal personal
income tax rate, marginal corporate tax rate, and public spending; for labor
market regulation, World Bank-administered surveys regarding the difficulty of
hiring workers, firing workers, cost of firing workers, and rigidity of working
hours; and for business regulation, from the same World Bank source, difficulty
to register a business, time to resolve insolvency, difficulty to register
property, and stock market-to-banking sector ratio in the financial system. For
more information on the factor loadings, see Knell and Srholec, 2007, pp.
42–45. 2006, pp. 774–776 for more details). Values range from 16.7 (Ireland) to
88.9 (United States).
Previous statistical evidence suggests that legislative
oversight generally increases fiscal discipline (Strauch & von Hagen, 1999;
von Hagen, 1992), so I expect a negative coefficient for this variable—the greater
the legislative oversight, the smaller the discretionary stimulus. For the debt
credibility model, I use a simple measurement of government debt: total
government liabilities as a per cent of GDP. I hypothesize a negative
coefficient for the debt variable, the expectation being that the size of a
government’s liabilities will induce fiscal restraint. For the partisan
politics model, the key variable is the strength of left parties.
The expectation is that left power ought to increase the
size of fiscal stimulus. I measure left power as a percentage of seats held by
left parties, as compiled from the Comparative Political Dataset III (CPDIII
hereafter) (Armingeon et al., 2011). While the literature on policy change has
achieved a modest consensus on the idea that constitutional structures have an
impact on the capacity of political parties to effect policy change (Kuhner,
2010), CPDIII does not contain a measurement of constitutional structures for
the East European cases, so I rely solely on left party strength. Finally, I
include four controls. First, since this paper supposes that governments
enacted discretionary fiscal stimulus principally in response to the social
consequences of the economic downturn, I include an unemployment rate variable.
I expect greater unemployment to be associated with greater fiscal stimulus.
Second, I control for the GDP growth/contraction, the intuition being that the
greater the decline in GDP, the more fiscal resources governments will be
willing to commit. Third, I include a rough measure of trade openness; total
exports plus total imports. Given the sensitivity of fiscal stimulus and
adjustments to import/export “leakage”, the greater the value of trade
openness, the smaller the stimulus is likely to be. Finally, I include a
measure of governments’ bank bailout costs, the intuition being that their size
will have a negative impact on countries’ willingness to commit additional
fiscal resources to bolstering the economy. Data for this last control comes
from Laeven and Valencia (2012), the rest is from the OECD.
No comments:
Post a Comment